Antitrust: Economic analysis:
Two-sided platform: Uber: Credit-card market:
Antisteering provisions:
Vertical restraints: Rule of reason: Relevant
market: Markets for complementary products:
When a cardholder uses a credit card to buy
something from a merchant, the transaction is facilitated by a credit-card
network. The network provides separate but interrelated services to both
cardholders and merchants. For cardholders, the network extends them credit,
which allows them to make purchases without cash and to defer payment until
later. Cardholders also can receive rewards based on the amount of money they
spend, such as airline miles, points for travel, or cash back. For merchants,
the network allows them to avoid the cost of processing transactions and
offers them quick, guaranteed payment. This saves merchants the trouble and
risk of extending credit to customers, and it increases the number and value of
sales that they can make.
By providing these services to cardholders and
merchants, credit-card companies bring these parties together, and therefore
operate what economists call a “two-sided platform.” As the name implies, a
two-sided platform offers different products or services to two different
groups who both depend on the platform to intermediate between them. See Evans
& Schmalensee, Markets With Two-Sided Platforms, Issues in Competition L. & Pol’y 667
(2008) (Evans & Schmalensee); Evans & Noel, Defining Antitrust Markets
When Firms Operate Two-Sided Platforms, 2005 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 667, 668
(Evans & Noel); Filistrucchi, Geradin, Van Damme, & Affeldt, Market
Definition in Two-Sided Markets: Theory and Practice, 10 J. Competition L.
& Econ. 293, 296 (2014) (Filistrucchi). For credit cards, that interaction
is a transaction. Thus, credit-card networks are a special type of two-sided
platform known as a “transaction” platform. See id., at 301, 304, 307;
Evans & Noel 676–678. The key feature of transaction platforms is that they
cannot make a sale to one side of the platform without simultaneously making a
sale to the other. See Klein, Lerner, Murphy, & Plache, Competition in
Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Interchange Fees,
73 Antitrust L. J. 571, 580, 583 (2006) (Klein). For example, no credit-card
transaction can occur unless both the merchant and the cardholder
simultaneously agree to use the same credit-card network. See Filistrucchi 301.
Two-sided platforms differ from traditional
markets in important ways. Most relevant here, two-sided platforms often
exhibit what economists call “indirect network effects.” Evans &
Schmalensee 667. Indirect network effects exist where the value of the
two-sided platform to one group of participants depends on how many members of
a different group participate. D. Evans & R. Schmalensee, Matchmakers: The
New Economics of Multisided Platforms 25 (2016). In other words, the value of
the services that a two-sided platform provides increases as the number of
participants on both sides of the platform increases. A credit card, for example,
is more valuable to cardholders when more merchants accept it, and is more
valuable to merchants when more cardholders use it. See Evans & Noel
686–687; Klein 580, 584. To ensure sufficient participation, two-sided
platforms must be sensitive to the prices that they charge each side. See Evans
& Schmalensee 675; Evans & Noel 680; Muris, Payment Card Regulation
and the (Mis)Application of the Economics of Two-Sided Markets, 2005 Colum.
Bus. L. Rev. 515, 532– 533 (Muris); Rochet & Tirole, Platform Competition
in Two-Sided Markets, J. Eur. Econ.
Assn. 990, 1013 (2003). Raising the price on side A risks losing participation
on that side, which decreases the value of the platform to side B. If
participants on side B leave due to this loss in value, then the platform has
even less value to side A—risking a feedback loop of declining demand. See
Evans & Schmalensee 675; Evans & Noel 680–681. Two-sided platforms
therefore must take these indirect network effects into account before making
a change in price on either side.
(…) The optimal price might require charging the
side with more elastic demand a below-cost (or even negative) price. See Muris
519, 550; Klein 579; Evans & Schmalensee 675; Evans & Noel 681. With
credit cards, for example, networks often charge cardholders a lower fee than
merchants because cardholders are more price sensitive.
(…) To maintain the loyalty of its cardholders,
Amex must continually invest in its rewards program. But, to fund those investments,
Amex must charge merchants higher fees than its rivals. Even though Amex’s
investments benefit merchants by encouraging cardholders to spend more money,
merchants would prefer not to pay the higher fees. One way that merchants try
to avoid them, while still enticing Amex’s cardholders to shop at their stores,
is by dissuading cardholders from using Amex at the point of sale. This
practice is known as “steering.”
Amex has prohibited steering since the 1950s by
placing antisteering provisions in its contracts with merchants. These antisteering
provisions prohibit merchants from implying a preference for non-Amex cards;
dissuading customers from using Amex cards; persuading customers to use other
cards; imposing any special restrictions, conditions, disadvantages, or fees on
Amex cards; or promoting other cards more than Amex. The antisteering provisions
do not, however, prevent merchants from steering customers toward debit cards,
checks, or cash.
(…) The Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit
reversed. United States v. American Express Co., 838 F. 3d 179,
184 (2016). It concluded that the credit-card market is one market, not two. Id.,
at 196–200. Evaluating the credit-card market as a whole, the Second Circuit
concluded that Amex’s antisteering provisions were not anticompetitive and did
not violate §1. See id., at 200–206.
We granted certiorari, 583 U. S. ___ (2017), and
now affirm.
In this case, both sides correctly acknowledge
that Amex’s antisteering provisions are vertical restraints— i.e., restraints
“imposed by agreement between firms at different levels of distribution.” Business
Electronics, at 730. The parties also correctly acknowledge that, like
nearly every other vertical restraint, the anti-steering provisions should be
assessed under the rule of reason. See Leegin, at 882; State Oil,
at 19; Business Electronics, at 726; Continental T. V., Inc. v. GTE
Sylvania Inc., 433 U. S. 36, 57 (1977).
(…) The relevant market is defined as “the area
of effective competition.” Typically this is the “arena within which significant
substitution in consumption or production occurs.”
(…) But courts should “combine” different
products or services into “a single market” when “that combination reflects
commercial realities.” (…) See also Brown Shoe Co. v. United States,
370 U. S. 294, 336– 337 (1962) (pointing out that “the definition of the
relevant market” must “‘correspond to the commercial realities’ of the
industry”).
(…) As explained, credit-card networks are
two-sided platforms. Due to indirect network effects, two-sided platforms
cannot raise prices on one side without risking a feedback loop of declining
demand. See Evans & Schmalensee 674–675; Evans & Noel 680–681.
And the fact that two-sided platforms charge one
side a price that is below or above cost reflects differences in the two sides’
demand elasticity, not market power or anticompetitive pricing. See Klein 574,
595, 598, 626. Price increases on one side of the platform likewise do not
suggest anticompetitive effects without some evidence that they have increased
the overall cost of the platform’s services. See id., at 575, 594, 626.
Thus, courts must include both sides of the platform—merchants and
cardholders—when defining the credit-card market.
(…) Newspapers that sell advertisements, for
example, arguably operate a two-sided platform because the value of an
advertisement increases as more people read the newspaper. Klein 579. But in
the newspaper-advertisement market, the indirect networks effects operate in
only one direction; newspaper readers are largely indifferent to the amount of
advertising that a newspaper contains. See Filistrucchi 321, 323, and n. 99;
Klein 583. Because of these weak indirect network effects, the market for
newspaper advertising behaves much like a one-sided market and should be
analyzed as such. See Filistrucchi 321; Times-Picayune Publishing Co. v.
United States, 345 U. S. 594, 610 (1953).
Contrary to the dissent’s assertion, post, at
11–12, merchant services and cardholder services are not complements. See
Filistrucchi 297 (“A two-sided market is different from markets for complementary
products, in which both products are bought by the same buyers, who, in their
buying decisions, can therefore be expected to take into account both prices”).
As already explained, credit-card companies are best understood as supplying
only one product—transactions—which is jointly consumed by a cardholder and a
merchant. See Klein 580. Merchant services and cardholder services are both
inputs to this single product. See ibid.
(…) To demonstrate anticompetitive effects on
the two-sided credit-card market as a whole, the plaintiffs must prove that
Amex’s antisteering provisions increased the cost of credit-card transactions
above a competitive level, reduced the number of credit-card transactions, or
otherwise stifled competition in the credit-card market.
In sum, the plaintiffs have not satisfied the
first step of the rule of reason. They have not carried their burden of proving
that Amex’s antisteering provisions have anticompetitive effects. Amex’s
business model has spurred robust interbrand competition and has increased the quality
and quantity of credit-card transactions. And it is “the promotion of
interbrand competition,” after all, that “is . . . ‘the primary purpose of the
antitrust laws.’”
Because Amex’s antisteering provisions do not
unreasonably restrain trade, we affirm the judgment of the Court of Appeals.
(U.S.S.C., June 25, 2018, Ohio v. American Express
Co., Docket 16-1454, J. Thomas)
Considérations
économiques liées au fonctionnement d’un système « two-sided
platform ».
Ici le marché
considéré est celui des cartes de crédit (considérées comme ne formant qu’un
seul marché).
La question posée
est celle de la compatibilité avec le droit des cartels de la clause contractuelle
que Amex insère dans ses contrats avec les commerçants pour leur interdire de
dissuader leurs clients de payer avec le système Amex (qui peut coûter plus
cher aux commerçants que les systèmes concurrents, pour financer de cette
manière des services plus avantageux aux consommateurs utilisateurs d’Amex,
dans le but de faire dépenser davantage ces consommateurs). La Cour juge ici
que cette clause contractuelle ne porte pas atteinte au droit des cartels, même
bien au contraire. Elle favorise la concurrence intermarques et augmente le
nombre et la qualité des transactions par cartes de crédit.
No comments:
Post a Comment