Antitrust: Rule of reason: Vertical restraint:
Reduced output, Increased prices, Decreased
quality:
Market power:
Horizontal restraints and market power:
To determine whether a restraint violates the
rule of reason, the parties agree that a three-step, burden-shifting framework
applies. Under this framework, the plaintiff has the initial burden to prove
that the challenged restraint has a substantial anticompetitive effect that
harms consumers in the relevant market. See J. Kalinowski, Antitrust Laws and
Trade Regulation§12.02[1] (2d ed. 2017) (Kalinowski); P. Areeda &
H.Hovenkamp, Fundamentals of Antitrust Law §15.02[B] (4th ed. 2017) (Areeda
& Hovenkamp); Capital Imaging Assoc., P. C. v. Mohawk Valley
Medical Associates, Inc., 996 F. 2d 537, 543 (CA2 1993). If the plaintiff
carries its burden, then the burden shifts to the defendant to show a
procompetitive rationale for the restraint. See Kalinowski §12.02[1]; Areeda
& Hovenkamp §15.02[B]; Capital Imaging Assoc., supra, at 543.
If the defendant makes this showing, then the burden shifts back to the
plaintiff to demonstrate that the procompetitive efficiencies could be
reasonably achieved through less anticompetitive means. See Kalinowski
§12.02[1]; Capital Imaging Assoc., supra, at 543.
Here, the parties ask us to decide whether the
plaintiffs have carried their initial burden of proving that Amex’s
antisteering provisions have an anticompetitive effect. The plaintiffs can make
this showing directly or indirectly. Direct evidence of anticompetitive effects
would be “‘proof of actual detrimental effects [on competition],’” FTC v.
Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U. S. 447, 460 (1986), such as
reduced output, increased prices, or decreased quality in the relevant market,
see Kalinowski §12.02[2]; Craftsman Limousine, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co.,
491 F. 3d 381, 390 (CA8 2007); Virginia Atlantic Airways Ltd. v. British
Airways PLC, 257 F. 3d 256, 264 (CA2 2001). Indirect evidence would be
proof of market power plus some evidence that the challenged restraint harms
competition. See Kalinowski §12.02[2]; Tops Markets, Inc. v. Quality
Markets, Inc., 142 F. 3d 90, 97 (CA2 1998); Spanish Broadcasting System
of Fla. v. Clear Channel Communications, Inc., 376 F. 3d 1065, 1073
(CA11 2004).
Because “legal presumptions that rest on
formalistic distinctions rather than actual market realities are generally
disfavored in antitrust law,” Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical
Services, Inc., 504 U. S. 451, 466–467 (1992), courts usually cannot
properly apply the rule of reason without an accurate definition of the
relevant market. “Without a definition of the market there is no way
to measure the defendant’s ability to lessen or destroy competition.” Walker
Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food Machinery & Chemical Corp., 382 U.
S. 172, 177 (1965); accord, Kalinowski §24.01[4][a]. Thus, the relevant market
is defined as “the area of effective competition.” Ibid. Typically this
is the “arena within which significant substitution in consumption or
production occurs.” Areeda & Hovenkamp §5.02; accord, Kalinowski
§24.02[1]; United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U. S. 563, 571 (1966).
But courts should “combine” different products or services into “a single
market” when “that combination reflects commercial realities.” Id., at
572; see also Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U. S. 294,
336– 337 (1962) (pointing out that “the definition of the relevant market” must
“‘correspond to the commercial realities’ of the industry”).
(…) Given that horizontal restraints involve
agreements between competitors not to compete in some way, this Court
concluded that it did not need to precisely define the relevant market to
conclude that these agreements were anticompetitive (…) But vertical restraints
are different (…) Vertical restraints often pose no risk to competition unless
the entity imposing them has market power, which cannot be evaluated unless the
Court first defines the relevant market. (fn. 7 p. 11).
As an initial matter, the plaintiffs’ argument
about merchant fees wrongly focuses on only one side of the two-sided
credit-card market. As explained, the credit-card market must be defined to
include both merchants and cardholders. Focusing on merchant fees alone misses
the mark because the product that credit-card companies sell is transactions,
not services to merchants, and the competitive effects of a restraint on
transactions cannot be judged by looking at merchants alone. Evidence of a
price increase on one side of a two-sided transaction platform cannot by
itself demonstrate an anticompetitive exercise of market power. To demonstrate
anticompetitive effects on the two-sided credit-card market as a whole, the
plaintiffs must prove that Amex’s antisteering provisions increased the cost of
credit-card transactions above a competitive level, reduced the number of
credit-card transactions, or otherwise stifled competition in the credit-card
market.
(…) That Amex allocates prices between merchants
and cardholders differently from Visa and MasterCard is simply not evidence
that it wields market power to achieve anticompetitive ends.
(…) “Market power is the ability to raise price
profitably by restricting output.” Areeda & Hovenkamp §5.01; accord,
Kodak, 504 U. S., at 464; Business Electronics, 485 U. S., at
723. This Court will “not infer competitive injury from price and output data
absent some evidence that tends to prove that output was restricted or prices
were above a competitive level.” Brooke Group Ltd., 509 U. S., at 237.
There is no such evidence in this case. The output of credit-card transactions
grew dramatically from 2008 to 2013, increasing 30%. See 838 F. 3d, at 206.
“Where . . . output is expanding at the same time prices are increasing,
rising prices are equally consistent with growing product demand.” Brooke
Group Ltd., supra, at 237.
The plaintiffs also failed to prove that Amex’s
antisteering provisions have stifled competition among credit-card companies.
To the contrary, while these agreements have been in place, the credit-card
market experienced expanding output and improved quality. Amex’s business
model spurred Visa and MasterCard to offer new premium card categories with
higher rewards. And it has increased the availability of card services,
including free banking and card-payment services for low-income customers who
otherwise would not be served. Indeed, between 1970 and 2001, the percentage of
households with credit cards more than quadrupled, and the proportion of
households in the bottom-income quintile with credit cards grew from just 2% to
over 38%.
Nor have Amex’s antisteering provisions ended
competition between credit-card networks with respect to merchant fees.
Instead, fierce competition between networks has constrained Amex’s ability to
raise these fees and has, at times, forced Amex to lower them. For instance,
when Amex raised its merchant prices between 2005 and 2010, some merchants
chose to leave its network. 88 F. Supp. 3d, at 197. And when its remaining
merchants complained, Amex stopped raising its merchant prices. Id., at
198. In another instance in the late 1980s and early 1990s, competition forced
Amex to offer lower merchant fees to “everyday spend” merchants—supermarkets,
gas stations, pharmacies, and the like—to persuade them to accept Amex.
In addition, Amex’s competitors have exploited
its higher merchant fees to their advantage. By charging lower merchant fees,
Visa, MasterCard, and Discover have achieved broader merchant
acceptance—approximately 3 million more locations than Amex.
And to compete even further with Amex, Visa and
MasterCard charge different merchant fees for different types of cards to
maintain their comparatively lower merchant fees and broader acceptance. Over
the long run, this competition has created a trend of declining merchant fees
in the credit-card market. In fact, since the first credit card was introduced
in the 1950s, merchant fees— including Amex’s merchant fees—have decreased by
more than half.
(…) Cf. Leegin, 551 U. S., at 890–891
(recognizing that vertical restraints can prevent retailers from free riding
and thus increase the availability of “tangible or intangible services or
promotional efforts” that enhance competition and consumer welfare).
Perhaps most importantly, antisteering
provisions do not prevent Visa, MasterCard, or Discover from competing against
Amex by offering lower merchant fees or promoting their broader merchant
acceptance.
In sum, the plaintiffs have not satisfied the
first step of the rule of reason. They have not carried their burden of proving
that Amex’s antisteering provisions have anticompetitive effects. Amex’s
business model has spurred robust interbrand competition and has increased the quality
and quantity of credit-card transactions. And it is “the promotion of
interbrand competition,” after all, that “is . . . ‘the primary purpose of the
antitrust laws.’”
Because Amex’s antisteering provisions do not
unreasonably restrain trade, we affirm the judgment of the Court of Appeals.
(U.S.S.C., June 25, 2018, Ohio v. American Express
Co., Docket 16-1454, J. Thomas)
Accords verticaux,
application des trois étapes de la « Rule of reason » (seule la
première des trois étapes est analysée en l’espèce, dans le contexte du marché
des cartes de crédit). La preuve de la réalisation des conditions de la
première étape incombe au demandeur : il doit démontrer que la conduite
illicite porte de manière substantielle atteinte à la concurrence, et qu’elle
occasionne un dommage aux consommateurs actifs au niveau du marché relevant. Si
le demandeur y parvient, le fardeau de la preuve passe au défendeur, qui doit
démontrer que sa conduite produit des effets favorables à la concurrence. Si le
défendeur y parvient, le fardeau de la preuve passe à nouveau au demandeur, qui
doit démontrer que ces effets favorables peuvent être obtenus par des moyens
moins dommageables à la concurrence.
Au niveau de la
première étape, l’atteinte à la concurrence peut consister en une diminution de
l’offre, en une augmentation des prix, ou en une diminution de qualité (dans
les limites du marché relevant) (preuves directes). Elle peut consister aussi
en un pouvoir de marché, qu’il faut prouver, tout en apportant en plus des
éléments de preuves démontrant que la conduite prétendument illicite porte
atteinte à la concurrence. Le pouvoir de marché peut être défini comme la
capacité d’augmenter les prix de manière profitable en réduisant l’offre.
Le marché relevant
doit être concrètement défini. Il s’agit typiquement du marché qui permet une
substitution significative.
La jurisprudence
Leegin reconnaît que les accords verticaux peuvent prévenir le « free
riding » des détaillants, entrainant ainsi une augmentation des services
de promotion et de vente offerts par ces détaillants, cela au profit de la
concurrence et des consommateurs.
No comments:
Post a Comment