Friday, December 7, 2018

Merger - Market Shares and Concentration


Competition
Merger
Market Shares and Concentration
Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (HHI)
Coordinated Effects and/or Unilateral Effects
Tacit Collusion = Oligopolistic Price Coordination = Conscious Parallelism
Commodity Product
Barriers to Entry

After determining the relevant product and geographic market, the next step is to “consider the likely effects of the proposed acquisition on competition within that market.” Swedish Match, 131 F. Supp. 2d at 166. The government can establish a presumption that the transaction will substantially lessen competition by showing that the acquisition would produce “‘a firm controlling an undue percentage share of the relevant market, and would result in a significant increase in the concentration of firms in that market.’” Heinz, 246 F.3d at 715 (quoting Philadelphia Nat’l Bank, 374 U.S. at 363); see also Baker Hughes, 908 F.2d at 982. “Market concentration . . . is often measured using the Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (‘HHI’).Heinz, 246 F.3d at 716; Swedish Match, 131 F. Supp. 2d at 166 n.11.
(…) Sufficiently high HHI figures establish a prima facie case of anticompetitiveness. H&R Block, 833 F. Supp. 2d at 71 (citing Heinz, 246 F.3d at 715 n.9).
The Merger Guidelines consider markets with an HHI above 2500 to be “highly concentrated,” and state that “mergers resulting in highly concentrated markets that involve an increase in the HHI of more than 200 points will be presumed to be likely to enhance market power.” Merger Guidelines § 5.3; Heinz, 246 F.3d at 715 (citing Baker Hughes, 908 F.2d at 982) (noting that significant increase in market concentration “establishes a ‘presumption’ that the merger will substantially lessen competition.”).
The North American chloride TiO2 market is dominated by five major producers. Tronox, Cristal, Chemours, Kronos, and Venator account for over 99% of chloride TiO2 sales in North America. Based on producer invoice and other pricing data analyzed by Dr. Hill, the market participants and their market shares in 2016 were as follows: Tronox , Cristal , Chemours , Kronos , and Venator . Post-Acquisition, the combined firm would have a market share of nearly 40% of North American sales of chloride TiO2.
Dr. Hill also calculated HHIs, based on the market share data. Dr. Hill’s calculations show that the Acquisition would increase the HHI by over 700 points, to a level of over 3000, which, under the Merger Guidelines, would render the post- Acquisition North American chloride TiO2 market a “highly concentrated” market. See Merger Guidelines § 5.3. These market share statistics demonstrate that the proposed Acquisition is presumptively anticompetitive. See FTC v. Staples, Inc., 190 F. Supp. 3d 100, 128 (D.D.C. 2016); Sysco, 113 F. Supp. 3d at 52-53.
Accordingly, based on the foregoing, Complaint Counsel has established a presumption that the effect of the Acquisition may be to substantially lessen competition. Under applicable authorities recited in section II.B.2., this presumption is sufficient to establish a prima facie case under Section 7 and shift the burden of rebuttal to Respondents. Moreover, in the instant case, the presumption is strengthened by additional evidence demonstrating a reasonable probability of anticompetitive effects, as discussed below.

Reasonable probability of anticompetitive effects
As the court explained in ProMedica Health Systems v. FTC, anticompetitive effects of a merger can include coordinated effects and/or unilateral effects.
The idea behind coordinated effects is that, “where rivals are few, firms will be able to coordinate their behavior, either by overt collusion or implicit understanding in order to restrict output and achieve profits above competitive levels.” H&R Block, 833 F. Supp. 2d at 77. . . . Unilateral-effects theory, on the other hand, holds that “the elimination of competition between two firms that results from their merger may alone constitute a substantial lessening of competition.” Merger Guidelines § 6 at 20.
Likelihood of coordinated effects: “Tacit collusion, sometimes called oligopolistic price coordination or conscious parallelism, describes the process, not in itself unlawful, by which firms in a concentrated market might in effect share monopoly power, setting their prices at a profit-maximizing, supracompetitive level by recognizing their shared economic interests and their interdependence with respect to price and output decisions.” Brooke Group v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 227 (1993). See also Merger Guidelines § 7 (Coordinated interaction includes an implied understanding or parallel accommodating conduct not pursuant to a prior understanding.).
(…) Chloride TiO2 is a commodity product. Markets for homogenous products are more susceptible to coordination (…) Each firm’s product is largely interchangeable with its rivals’ products (…) In this case, given the small number of market participants in the relevant market, and the commodity nature of chloride TiO2, the market is fairly characterized as an oligopoly (…) (“The titanium dioxide market has been described as an ‘oligopoly,’ as TiO2 is a ‘commodity-like product with no substitutes, the market is dominated by a handful of firms, and there are substantial barriers to entry’”).
(…) “Regular monitoring by suppliers of one another’s prices or customers can indicate that the terms offered to customers are relatively transparent.” Merger Guidelines § 7.2. See also Oracle, 331 F. Supp. 2d at 1166 (“Without homogeneity or transparency, the market conditions are not conducive to coordinated effects, either tacit or express”). The evidence in this case shows that TiO2 suppliers monitor, and are able to observe, significant moves by their competitors, including as to price and output, from public statements by competitors and information obtained from customers (…) Tronox and Cristal monitor and analyze public statements by competitors such as quarterly earnings updates, presentations at industry conferences, and ratings agency meetings (…) The information provided in public earnings calls and similar public presentations can be specific. Tronox discusses in its quarterly results earnings calls such matters as changes in sales volume, changes in the selling prices by region, margin information, and operation related information such as relative plant utilization rate and inventory levels. (…) The Acquisition will increase the competitive information available to market participants through earnings calls and similar public presentations. Tronox, Chemours, Kronos, and Venator are publically traded companies, and therefore required to report earnings and similar business information to investors and others in the ordinary course of business. Presently, Cristal is a privately held company. With the merger, all participants will be reporting as public companies.
Complaint Counsel’s additional theory of likely anticompetitive effects, that the Acquisition will enable the combined entity to engage in strategic output withholding (unilateral effects), has been fully considered, together with the relevant evidence in the record. However, findings or conclusions as to the likelihood of anticompetitive unilateral effects are unnecessary because the presumption of anticompetitive effects, based on market concentration evidence, combined with the evidence of likely coordinated effects, is already sufficient to make a strong prima facie case of likely anticompetitive effects. Further determining the likelihood of unilateral effects would not affect this result.

Rebuttal
As noted in section II.B.2. above, a defendant may rebut a prima facie showing of likely anticompetitive effects with evidence that anticompetitive effects are not likely to result from the merger, or that procompetitive benefits, such as efficiencies, outweigh any likely anticompetitive effects. See, e.g., Baker Hughes, 908 F.2d at 985; Polypore, 2010 WL 9549988, at *9.
(Entry; Efficiencies; Output increasing synergies (vertical integration); Cost savings).
Respondents have failed to rebut the prima facie proof that the Acquisition is reasonably likely to have anticompetitive effects in the relevant market for the sale of chloride TiO2 in North America. Accordingly, the evidence proves that the planned Acquisition may substantially lessen competition in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act and Section 5 of the FTC Act.


(FTC, Office of Administrative Law Judges, In the Matter of Tronox/Cristal USA, Dec. 7, 2018, Docket No. 9377)

No comments:

Post a Comment